New Keynesian economics
Economics |
---|
Phillips curve graph, illustrating an economic principle |
|
|
By application |
|
Lists |
|
New Keynesian economics is a school of contemporary macroeconomics that strives to provide microeconomic foundations for Keynesian economics. It developed partly as a response to criticisms of Keynesian macroeconomics by adherents of New Classical macroeconomics.
Two main assumptions define the New Keynesian approach to macroeconomics. Like the New Classical approach, New Keynesian macroeconomic analysis usually assumes that households and firms have rational expectations. But the two schools differ in that New Keynesian analysis usually assumes a variety of market failures. In particular, New Keynesians assume that there is imperfect competition[1] in price and wage setting to help explain why prices and wages can become "sticky", which means they do not adjust instantaneously to changes in economic conditions.
Wage and price stickiness, and the other market failures present in New Keynesian models, imply that the economy may fail to attain full employment. Therefore, New Keynesians argue that macroeconomic stabilization by the government (using fiscal policy) or by the central bank (using monetary policy) can lead to a more efficient macroeconomic outcome than a laissez faire policy would.
Development
1970s
The first wave of New Keynesian economics developed in the late 1970s. The first model of Sticky information was developed by Stanley Fischer in his 1977 article, Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule.[2] He adopted a "staggered" or "overlapping" contract model. Suppose that there are two unions in the economy, who take turns to choose wages. When it is a union's turn, it chooses the wages it will set for the next two periods. This contrasts with John B. Taylor's model where the nominal wage is constant over the contract life, as was subsequently developed in his two articles, one in 1979 "Staggered wage setting in a macro model'.[3] and one in 1980 "Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts".[4] Both Taylor and Fischer contracts share the feature that only the unions setting the wage in the current period are using the latest information: wages in half of the economy still reflect old information. The Taylor model had sticky nominal wages in addition to the sticky information: nominal wages had to be constant over the length of the contract (two periods). These early new Keynesian theories were based on the basic idea that, given fixed nominal wages, a monetary authority (central bank) can control the employment rate. Since wages are fixed at a nominal rate, the monetary authority can control the real wage (wage values adjusted for inflation) by changing the money supply and thus effect the employment rate.[5]
1980s
Menu costs and Imperfect Competition
In the 1980s the key concept of using menu costs in a framework of imperfect competition to explain price stickiness was developed.[6] The concept of a lump-sum cost (menu cost) to changing the price was originally introduced by Sheshinski and Weiss (1977) in their paper looking at the effect of inflation on the frequency of price-changes.[7] The idea of applying it as a general theory of Nominal Price Rigidity was simultaneously put forward by several economists in 1985–6. George Akerlof and Janet Yellen put forward the idea that due to bounded rationality firms will not want to change their price unless the benefit is more than a small amount.[8][9] This bounded rationality leads to inertia in nominal prices and wages which can lead to output fluctuating at constant nominal prices and wages. Gregory Mankiw took the menu-cost idea and focused on the welfare effects of changes in output resulting from sticky prices.[10] Michael Parkin also put forward the idea.[11] Although the approach initially focused mainly on the rigidity of nominal prices, it was extended to wages and prices by Olivier Blanchard and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki in their influential article Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand .[12] Huw Dixon and Claus Hansen showed that even if menu costs applied to a small sector of the economy, this would influence the rest of the economy and lead to prices in the rest of the economy becoming less responsive to changes in demand.[13]
While some studies suggested that menu costs are too small to have much of an aggregate impact, Laurence Ball and David Romer showed in 1990 that real rigidities could interact with nominal rigidities to create significant disequilibrium.[14] Real rigidities occur whenever a firm is slow to adjust its real prices in response to a changing economic environment. For example, a firm can face real rigidities if it has market power or if its costs for inputs and wages are locked-in by a contract.[15] Ball and Romer argued that real rigidities in the labor market keep a firm's costs high, which makes firms hesitant to cut prices and lose revenue. The expense created by real rigidities combined with the menu cost of changing prices makes it less likely that firm will cut prices to a market clearing level.[16]
Even if prices are perfectly flexible, imperfect competition can affect the influence of fiscal policy in terms of the multiplier. Huw Dixon and Gregory Mankiw developed independently simple general equilibrium models showing that the fiscal multiplier could be increasing with the degree of imperfect competition in the output market.[17][18] The reason for this is that imperfect competition in the output market tends to reduce the real wage, leading to the household substituting away from consumption towards leisure. When government spending is increased, the corresponding increase in lump-sum taxation causes both leisure and consumption to decrease (assuming that they are both a normal good). The greater the degree of imperfect competition in the output market, the lower the real wage and hence the more the reduction falls on leisure (i.e. households work more) and less on consumption. Hence the fiscal multiplier is less than one, but increasing in the degree of imperfect competition in the output market.[19]
The Calvo staggered contracts model
In 1983 Guillermo Calvo wrote "Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework".[20] The original article was written in a continuous time mathematical framework, but nowadays is mostly used in its discrete time version. The Calvo model has become the most common way to model nominal rigidity in new Keynesian models. There is a probability that the firm can reset its price in any one period h (the hazard rate), or equivalently the probability (1-h) that the price will remain unchanged in that period (the survival rate). The probability h is sometimes called the "Calvo probability" in this context. In the Calvo model the crucial feature is that the price-setter does not know how long the nominal price will remain in place, in contrast to the Taylor model where the length of contract is known ex ante.
Coordination failure
Coordination failure was another important new Keynesian concept developed as another potential explanation for recessions and unemployment.[22] In recessions a factory can go idle even though there are people willing to work in it, and people willing to buy its production if they had jobs. In such a scenario, economic downturns appear to be the result of coordination failure: The invisible hand fails to coordinate the usual, optimal, flow of production and consumption.[23] Russell Cooper and Andrew John's 1988 paper Coordinating Coordination Failures in Keynesian Models expressed a general form of coordination as models with multiple equilibria where agents could coordinate to improve (or at least not harm) each of their respective situations.[21][24] Cooper and John based their work on earlier models including Peter Diamond's 1982 coconut model, which demonstrated a case of coordination failure involving search and matching theory.[25] In Diamond's model producers are more likely to produce if they see others producing. The increase in possible trading partners increases the likelihood of a given producer finding someone to trade with. As in other cases of coordination failure, Diamond's model has multiple equilibria, and the welfare of one agent is dependent on the decisions of others.[26] Diamond's model is an example of a "thick-market externality" that causes markets to function better when more people and firms participate in them.[27] Other potential sources of coordination failure include self-fulfilling prophecies. If a firm anticipates a fall in demand, they might cut back on hiring. A lack of job vacancies might worry workers who then cut back on their consumption. This fall in demand meets the firm's expectations, but it is entirely due to the firm's own actions.
Labor market failures: Efficiency wages
New Keynesians offered explanations for the failure of the labor market to clear. In a Walrasian market, unemployed workers bid down wages until the demand for workers meets the supply.[28] If markets are Walrasian, the ranks of the unemployed would be limited to workers transitioning between jobs and workers who choose not to work because wages are too low to attract them.[29] They developed several theories explaining why markets might leave willing workers unemployed.[30] The most important of these theories, new Keynesians was the efficiency wage theory used to explain long-term effects of previous unemployment, where short-term increases in unemployment become permanent and lead to higher levels of unemployment in the long-run.[31]
In efficiency wage models, workers are paid at levels that maximize productivity instead of clearing the market.[32] For example, in developing countries, firms might pay more than a market rate to ensure their workers can afford enough nutrition to be productive.[33] Firms might also pay higher wages to increase loyalty and morale, possibly leading to better productivity.[34] Firms can also pay higher than market wages to forestall shirking. Shirking models were particularly influential.[35]Carl Shapiro and Joseph Stiglitz's 1984 paper Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device created a model where employees tend to avoid work unless firms can monitor worker effort and threaten slacking employees with unemployment.[36][37] If the economy is at full employment, a fired shirker simply moves to a new job.[38] Individual firms pay their workers a premium over the market rate to ensure their workers would rather work and keep their current job instead of shirking and risk having to move to a new job. Since each firm pays more than market clearing wages, the aggregated labor market fails to clear. This creates a pool of unemployed laborers and adds to the expense of getting fired. Workers not only risk a lower wage, they risk being stuck in the pool of unemployed. Keeping wages above market clearing levels creates a serious disincentive to shirk that makes workers more efficient even though it leaves some willing workers unemployed.[39]
1990s
The new neoclassical synthesis
In the early 1990s, economists began to combine the elements of new Keynesian economics developed in the 1980s and earlier with Real Business Cycle Theory. RBC models were dynamic but assumed perfect competition; new Keynesian models were primarily static but based on imperfect competition. The New neoclassical synthesis essentially combined the dynamic aspects of RBC with imperfect competition and nominal rigidities of new Keynesian models. Tack Yun was one of the first to do this, in a model which used the Calvo pricing model.[40] Goodfriend and King proposed a list of four elements that are central to the new synthesis: intertemporal optimization, rational expectations, imperfect competition, and costly price adjustment (menu costs).[41][42] Goodfriend and King also find that the consensus models produce certain policy implications: whilst monetary policy can affect real output in the short-run, but there is no long-run trade-off: money is not neutral in the short-run but it is in the long-run. Inflation has negative welfare effects. It is important for central banks to maintain credibility through rules based policy like inflation targeting.
Taylor Rule
In 1993,[43] John B Taylor formulated the idea of a Taylor rule, which is a monetary-policy rule that stipulates how much the central bank should change the nominal interest rate in response to changes in inflation, output, or other economic conditions. In particular, the rule stipulates that for each one-percent increase in inflation, the central bank should raise the nominal interest rate by more than one percentage point. This aspect of the rule is often called the Taylor principle.
According to Taylor's original version of the rule, the nominal interest rate should respond to divergences of actual inflation rates from target inflation rates and of actual Gross Domestic Product (GDP) from potential GDP:
In this equation, is the target short-term nominal interest rate (e.g. the federal funds rate in the US, the Bank of England base rate in the UK), is the rate of inflation as measured by the GDP deflator, is the desired rate of inflation, is the assumed equilibrium real interest rate, is the logarithm of real GDP, and is the logarithm of potential output, as determined by a linear trend.
The New Keynesian Phillips curve
The New Keynesian Phillips curve was originally derived by Roberts in 1995,[44] and has since been used in most state-of-the-art New Keynesian DSGE models [45] The new Keynesian Phillips curve says that this period's inflation depends on current output and the expectations of next period's inflation. The curve is derived from the dynamic Calvo model of pricing and in mathematical terms is:
The current period t expectations of next period's inflation are incorporated as , where is the discount factor. The constant captures the response of inflation to output, and is largely determined by the probability of changing price in any period, which is :
- .
The less rigid nominal prices are (the higher is ), the greater the effect of output on current inflation.
The Science of Monetary Policy
The ideas developed in the 1990s were put together to develop the new Keynesian Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium used to analyze monetary policy. This culminated in the three equation new Keynesian model found in the survey by Richard Clarida, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler in the Journal of Economic Literature,.[46][47] It combines the two equations of the new Keynesian Phillips curve and the Taylor rule with the dynamic IS curve derived from the optimal dynamic consumption equation (household's Euler equation).
These three equations formed a relatively simple model which could be used for the theoretical analysis of policy issues. However, the model was oversimplified in some respects (for example, there is no capital or investment). Also, it does not perform well empirically.
2000s
In the new millennium there have been several advances in new Keynesian economics.
The introduction of imperfectly competitive labor markets
Whilst the models of the 1990s focused on sticky prices in the output market, in 2000 Christopher Erceg, Dale Henderson and Andrew Levin adopted the Blanchard and Kiyotaki model of unionized labor markets by combining it with the Calvo pricing approach and introduced it into a new Keynesian DSGE model.[48]
The development of complicated DSGE models.
In order to have models that worked well with the data and could be used for policy simulations, quite complicated new Keynesian models were developed with several features. Seminal papers were published by Frank Smets and Rafael Wouters[49][50] and also Lawrence J. Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum and Charles Evans[51] The common features of these models included:
- habit persistence. The marginal utility of consumption depends on past consumption.
- Calvo pricing in both output and product markets, with indexation so that when wages and prices are not explicitly reset, they are updated for inflation.
- capital adjustment costs and variable capital utilization.
- new shocks
- demand shocks, which affect the marginal utility of consumption
- markup shocks that influence the desired markup of price over marginal cost.
- monetary policy is represented by a Taylor rule.
- Bayesian estimation methods.
Sticky information
The idea of Sticky information found in Fischer's model was later developed by Gregory Mankiw and Ricardo Reis.[52] This added a new feature to Fischer's model: there is a fixed probability that you can replan your wages or prices each period. Using quarterly data, they assumed a value of 25%: that is, each quarter 25% of randomly chosen firms/unions can plan a trajectory of current and future prices based on current information. Thus if we consider the current period: 25% of prices will be based on the latest information available; the rest on information that was available when they last were able to replan their price trajectory. Mankiw and Reis found that the model of sticky information provided a good way of explaining inflation persistence.
Sticky information models do not have nominal rigidity: firms or unions are free to choose different prices or wages for each period. It is the information that is sticky, not the prices. Thus when a firm gets lucky and can re-plan its current and future prices, it will choose a trajectory of what it believes will be the optimal prices now and in the future. In general, this will involve setting a different price every period covered by the plan. This is at odds with the empirical evidence on prices.[53][54] There are now many studies of price rigidity in different countries: the US,[55] the Eurozone,[56] the UK [57] and others. These studies all show that whilst there are some sectors where prices change frequently, there are also other sectors where prices remain fixed over time. The lack of sticky prices in the sticky information model is inconsistent with the behavior of prices in most of the economy. This has led to attempts to formulate a "dual Stickiness" model that combines sticky information with sticky prices.[54][58]
Policy implications
New Keynesian economists agree with New Classical economists that in the long run, the classical dichotomy holds: changes in the money supply are neutral. However, because prices are sticky in the New Keynesian model, an increase in the money supply (or equivalently, a decrease in the interest rate) does increase output and lower unemployment in the short run. Furthermore, some New Keynesian models confirm the non-neutrality of money under several conditions.[59][60]
Nonetheless, New Keynesian economists do not advocate using expansive monetary policy for short run gains in output and employment, as it would raise inflationary expectations and thus store up problems for the future. Instead, they advocate using monetary policy for stabilization. That is, suddenly increasing the money supply just to produce a temporary economic boom is not recommended as eliminating the increased inflationary expectations will be impossible without producing a recession.
However, when the economy is hit by some unexpected external shock, it may be a good idea to offset the macroeconomic effects of the shock with monetary policy. This is especially true if the unexpected shock is one (like a fall in consumer confidence) which tends to lower both output and inflation; in that case, expanding the money supply (lowering interest rates) helps by increasing output while stabilizing inflation and inflationary expectations.
Studies of optimal monetary policy in New Keynesian DSGE models have focused on interest rate rules (especially 'Taylor rules'), specifying how the central bank should adjust the nominal interest rate in response to changes in inflation and output. (More precisely, optimal rules usually react to changes in the output gap, rather than changes in output per se.) In some simple New Keynesian DSGE models, it turns out that stabilizing inflation suffices, because maintaining perfectly stable inflation also stabilizes output and employment to the maximum degree desirable. Blanchard and Galí have called this property the ‘divine coincidence’.[61]
However, they also show that in models with more than one market imperfection (for example, frictions in adjusting the employment level, as well as sticky prices), there is no longer a 'divine coincidence', and instead there is a tradeoff between stabilizing inflation and stabilizing employment.[62] Further, while some macroeconomists believe that New Keynesian models are on the verge of being useful for quarter-to-quarter quantitative policy advice, disagreement exists.[63]
Recently, it was shown that the divine coincidence does not necessarily hold in the non-linear form of the standard New-Keynesian model.[64] This property would only hold if the monetary authority is set to keep the inflation rate at exactly 0%. At any other desired target for the inflation rate, there is an endogenous trade-off, even under the absence real imperfections such as sticky wages, and the divine coincidence no longer holds.
Relation to other macroeconomic schools
Over the years, a sequence of 'new' macroeconomic theories related to or opposed to Keynesianism have been influential.[65] After World War II, Paul Samuelson used the term neoclassical synthesis to refer to the integration of Keynesian economics with neoclassical economics. The idea was that the government and the central bank would maintain rough full employment, so that neoclassical notions—centered on the axiom of the universality of scarcity—would apply. John Hicks' IS/LM model was central to the neoclassical synthesis.
Later work by economists such as James Tobin and Franco Modigliani involving more emphasis on the microfoundations of consumption and investment was sometimes called neo-Keynesianism. It is often contrasted with the post-Keynesianism of Paul Davidson, which emphasizes the role of fundamental uncertainty in economic life, especially concerning issues of private fixed investment.
New Keynesianism is a response to Robert Lucas and the new classical school.[66] That school criticized the inconsistencies of Keynesianism in the light of the concept of "rational expectations". The new classicals combined a unique market-clearing equilibrium (at full employment) with rational expectations. The New Keynesians use "microfoundations" to demonstrate that price stickiness hinders markets from clearing. Thus, the rational expectations-based equilibrium need not be unique.
Whereas the neoclassical synthesis hoped that fiscal and monetary policy would maintain full employment, the new classicals assumed that price and wage adjustment would automatically attain this situation in the short run. The new Keynesians, on the other hand, see full employment as being automatically achieved only in the long run, since prices are "sticky" in the short run. Government and central-bank policies are needed because the "long run" may be very long.
Keynes' stress on the importance of centralized coordination of macroeconomic policies (e.g., monetary and fiscal stimulus) and of international economic institutions such as the World Bank and International Monetary Fund (IMF), and of the maintenance of a controlled trading system was emphasized during the 2008 global financial and economic crisis. This has been reflected in the work of IMF economists[67] and of Donald Markwell.[68]
See also
- Calvo (staggered) contracts
- 2008–2009 Keynesian resurgence
- New neoclassical synthesis
- Sticky prices
- Welfare cost of business cycles
- Taylor Contracts (economics)
References
- ↑ The role of imperfect competition in new Keynesian economics, Chapter 4 of Surfing Economics by Huw Dixon
- ↑ Fischer, S. (1977). "Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule". Journal of Political Economy. 85 (1): 191–205. doi:10.1086/260551. JSTOR 1828335.
- ↑ John B Taylor (1979), 'Staggered wage setting in a macro model'. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 69 (2), pp. 108–13
- ↑ John B Taylor (1980). "Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts," Journal of Political Economy, 88(1), pages 1-23, February.
- ↑ Mankiw, N. Gregory (December 1990). "A Quick Refresher Course in Macroeconomics". Journal of Economic Literature, volume 28, pages 1645–1660. doi:10.3386/w3256. page 1658.
- ↑ Dixon, Huw (2001). "The Role of imperfect competition in new Keynesian economics" (PDF). Surfing Economics: Essays for the Inquiring Economist. New York: Palgrave. ISBN 0333760611.
- ↑ Sheshinski, Eytan; Weiss, Yoram (1977). "Inflation and Costs of Price Adjustment". Review of Economic Studies. 44 (2): 287–303. doi:10.2307/2297067. JSTOR 2297067.
- ↑ Akerlof, George A.; Yellen, Janet L. (1985). "Can Small Deviations from Rationality Make Significant Differences to Economic Equilibria?". American Economic Review. 75 (4): 708–720. JSTOR 1821349.
- ↑ Akerlof, George A.; Yellen, Janet L. (1985). "A Near-rational Model of the Business Cycle, with Wage and Price Intertia". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 100 (5): 823–838. doi:10.1093/qje/100.Supplement.823.
- ↑ Mankiw, N. Gregory (1985). "Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeconomic Model of Monopoly". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 100 (2): 529–538. doi:10.2307/1885395. JSTOR 1885395.
- ↑ Parkin, Michael (1986). "The Output-Inflation Trade-off When Prices Are Costly to Change". Journal of Political Economy. 94 (1): 200–224. doi:10.1086/261369. JSTOR 1831966.
- ↑ Blanchard, O.; Kiyotaki, N. (1987). "Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand". American Economic Review. 77 (4): 647–666. JSTOR 1814537.
- ↑ Dixon, Huw; Hansen, Claus (1999). "A Mixed Industrial Structure Magnifies the Importance of Menu Costs". European Economic Review. 43 (8): 1475–1499. doi:10.1016/S0014-2921(98)00029-4.
- ↑ Ball L. and Romer D (1990). Real Rigidities and the Non-neutrality of Money, Review of Economic Studies, volume 57, pages: 183-203
- ↑ Romer, David (2005). Advanced Macroeconomics. New York: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-287730-4., pp 380–381.
- ↑ Mankiw, N. Gregory (1990).
- ↑ Huw Dixon, a simple model of imperfect competition with Walrasian features, Oxford Economic Papers, (1987), 39, 134–160
- ↑ Gregory Mankiw (1988), Imperfect competition and the Keynesian cross, Economics Letters, volume 26, pages 7-13
- ↑ Costa L, Dixon H. (2011), "Fiscal Policy Under Imperfect Competition with Flexible Prices: An Overview and Survey", Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal, Vol. 5, 2011-3. doi:10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2011-3.
- ↑ Calvo, Guillermo A. (1983). "Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework". Journal of Monetary Economics 12 (3): 383–398. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(83)90060-0
- 1 2 Cooper, Russel; John, Andrew (1988). "Coordinating Coordination Failures in Keynesian Models". The Quarterly Journal of Economics 103 (3): 441–463. doi:10.2307/1885539. JSTOR 1885539, page 446
- ↑ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2008). "New Keynesian Economics". The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty. Retrieved 27 September 2010.
- ↑ Howitt, Peter (2002). "Coordination failures". In Snowdon, Brian; Vane, Howard. An Encyclopedia of Macroeconomics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-84064-387-9, pages 140-1.
- ↑ Howitt (2002), page142
- ↑ Diamond, Peter A. (October 1982). "Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilibrium". Journal of Political Economy 90 (5): 881–894. doi:10.2307/1837124.
- ↑ Cooper and John (1988), pages 452-3.
- ↑ Mankiw, N. Gregory; Romer, David (1991). New Keynesian economics 1. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. ISBN 0-262-13266-4, page 8
- ↑ Romer (2005), page 438
- ↑ Romer (2005) pages 437–439
- ↑ Romer 2005, p. 437.
- ↑ Snowdon, Brian; Vane, Howard (2005). Modern Macroeconomics. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. ISBN 978-1-84542-208-0, page 384
- ↑ Froyen, Richard (1990). Macroeconomics, Theories and Policies (3rd ed.). New York: Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-02-339482-9. page 357
- ↑ Romer (2005), page 439
- ↑ Froyen (1990), page 358
- ↑ Romer (2005), page 448
- ↑ Shapiro, C.; Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). "Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device". The American Economic Review 74 (3): 433–444. doi:10.2307/1804018
- ↑ Snowden and Vane (2005), page 390
- ↑ Romer (2005), page 453.
- ↑ Snowden and Vane (2005), page 390.
- ↑ Yun, Tack, (1996). "Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity, and business cycles," Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, vol. 37(2-3), pages 345-370, April.
- ↑ Goodfriend, Marvin; King, Robert G (1997), "The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy", NBER Macroeconomics Annual, NBER Chapters (National Bureau of Economic Research) 12: 231–83, JSTOR 3585232.
- ↑ Snowden and Vane 2005, page 411
- ↑ Taylor, John B. (1993). "Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice" (PDF). Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy. 39: 195–214. (The rule is introduced on page 202.)
- ↑ Roberts, John M. (1995). "New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 27 (4): 975–984. doi:10.2307/2077783. JSTOR 2077783.
- ↑ Romer, David (2012). "Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Models of Fluctuation". Advanced Macroeconomics. New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin. pp. 312–364. ISBN 978-0-07-351137-5.
- ↑ Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (2000)
- ↑ Clarida, Richard; Galí, Jordi; Gertler, Mark (2000). "Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 115 (1): 147–180. doi:10.1162/003355300554692.
- ↑ Erceg C, Henderson D, and Levin A. (2000), Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts, Journal of Monetary Economics, 46, pages 281-313
- ↑ Frank Smets & Raf Wouters, 2003. "An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area," Journal of the European Economic Association, MIT Press, vol. 1(5), pages 1123-1175, doi=10.1162/154247603770383415.
- ↑ Frank Smets & Rafael Wouters, 2007. "Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach," American Economic Review, American Economic Association, vol. 97(3), pages 586-606, June.
- ↑ Christiano, Lawrence; Eichenbaum, Martin; Evans, Charles (2005). "Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy" (PDF). Journal of Political Economy. 113 (1): 1–45. doi:10.1086/426038.
- ↑ Mankiw, N. G.; Reis, R. (2002). "Sticky Information Versus Sticky Prices: A Proposal To Replace The New Keynesian Phillips Curve". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117 (4): 1295–1328. doi:10.1162/003355302320935034.
- ↑ Chari, V. V.; Kehoe, Patrick J.; McGrattan, Ellen R. (2008). "New Keynesian Models: Not Yet Useful for Policy Analysis" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 409.
- 1 2 Knotec, Edward S. II (2010). "A Tale of Two Rigidities: Sticky Prices in a Sticky-Information Environment". Journal of Money, Credit and Banking. 42 (8): 1543–1564. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2010.00353.x.
- ↑ Klenow, Peter J.; Kryvtsov, Oleksiy (2008). "State-Dependent or Time-Dependent Pricing: Does It Matter For Recent U.S. Inflation?". The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 123 (3): 863–904. doi:10.1162/qjec.2008.123.3.863.
- ↑ Álvarez, Luis J.; Dhyne, Emmanuel; Hoeberichts, Marco; Kwapil, Claudia; Le Bihan, Hervé; Lünnemann, Patrick; Martins, Fernando; Sabbatini, Roberto; Stahl, Harald; Vermeulen, Philip; Vilmunen, Jouko (2006). "Sticky Prices in the Euro Area: A Summary of New Micro-Evidence". Journal of the European Economic Association. 4 (2-3): 575–584. doi:10.1162/jeea.2006.4.2-3.575.
- ↑ Bunn, Philip; Ellis, Colin (2012). "Examining The Behaviour Of Individual UK Consumer Prices". The Economic Journal. 122 (558): F35–F55. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2011.02490.x.
- ↑ Dupor, Bill; Kitamura, Tomiyuki; Tsuruga, Takayuki (2010). "Integrating Sticky Prices and Sticky Information". Review of Economics and Statistics. 92 (3): 657–669. doi:10.1162/REST_a_00017.
- ↑ Benchimol, J., Fourçans, A. (2012), Money and risk in a DSGE framework : A Bayesian application to the Eurozone, Journal of Macroeconomics, vol. 34, pp. 95-111.
- ↑ Benchimol, J., 2015, Money in the production function: a new Keynesian DSGE perspective, Southern Economic Journal, Volume 82, Issue 1, pp. 152-184.
- ↑ Blanchard, Olivier; Galí, Jordi (2007). "Real wage rigidities and the New Keynesian model". Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. 39 (1): 35–65. doi:10.1111/j.1538-4616.2007.00015.x.
- ↑ Blanchard, Olivier; Galí, Jordi (2007). "A New Keynesian model with unemployment" (PDF). CFS working paper 2007/08, Center for Financial Studies, Goethe University, Frankfurt.
- ↑ Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, New Keynesian Models: Not Yet Useful for Policy Analysis, July 2008
- ↑ Alves, S. A. L., 2014, "Lack of Divine Coincidence in New-Keynesian Models", Journal of Monetary Economics 67: 33-46.
- ↑ Michael Woodford (1999), 'Revolution and evolution in 20th century macroeconomics, mimeo, Columbia University.
- ↑ Gali, Jordi (2015). Monetary Policy, Inflation and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework and Its Applications (second edition), Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford, ISBN 978-0-691-16478-6. Pages 5-6.
- ↑ Fiscal Policy for the Crisis, prepared by the IMF Fiscal Affairs and Research Departments (Antonio Spilimbergo, Steve Symansky, Olivier Blanchard, and Carlo Cottarelli)December 29, 2008
- ↑ Donald Markwell, John Maynard Keynes and International Relations: Economic Paths to War and Peace, Oxford University Press, 2006.
Further reading
- Clarida, Richard; Galí, Jordi; Gertler, Mark (1999). "The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective". Journal of Economic Literature. 37 (4): 1661–1707. doi:10.1257/jel.37.4.1661. JSTOR 2565488.
- Robert J. Gordon Gordon, Robert (1990), What is New-Keynesian Economics?, Journal of Economic Literature.
- Dixon, Huw (2008), New Keynesian Economics, New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics New Keynesian macroeconomics. doi:10.1057/9780230226203.1184.
- Mankiw, N. Gregory (2008). "New Keynesian Economics". In David R. Henderson (ed.). Concise Encyclopedia of Economics (2nd ed.). Indianapolis: Library of Economics and Liberty. ISBN 978-0865976658. OCLC 237794267.
- Rowe, Nick. "The Growth Stages of the New Keynesian Model". Worthwhile Canadian Initiative. Retrieved 24 July 2014.