Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle
Economics |
---|
Phillips curve graph, illustrating an economic principle |
|
|
By application |
|
Lists |
|
In developmental economics, the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle (also called the Growth-Inequality-Poverty Triangle or GIP Triangle) refers to the idea that a country's change in poverty can be fully determined by its change in income growth and income inequality. According to the model, a development strategy must then also be based on income growth and income inequality.[1][2] The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle model was created by François Bourguignon, the former Chief Economist (2003-2007) of the World Bank.
Background
The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle was originally introduced by Bourguignon in a paper presented at the Conference on Poverty, Inequality and Growth in Paris on November 13, 2003. A modified version of the paper was presented at the Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations in New Delhi on February 4, 2004.[2]
Economists working for international organizations like the World Bank use the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle to create poverty reduction strategies that include both steps to reduce inequality and stimulate growth. Economists have used the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle to study poverty in both developing countries and developed countries, including China, Egypt, India, Mexico, and Nigeria.[3] [2] [4]
In 2013, a study of the 138 countries over the period 2005 to 2010 found that the basic ideas of Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle hold and that both growth and inequality impact absolute poverty as Bourguignon described.[5]
Model
The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle can be drawn as a triangle with arrows pointing out of each corner. At the top of the triangle is "absolute poverty." This refers to the percent of the population below the income poverty line. At the bottom left of the triangle is "inequality" or "distribution." This refers to differences in income across a population. At the bottom right of the triangle is "growth." This refers to the change in income for a population (for example, a change in GDP).[2]
The arrows pointing out of "absolute poverty," "growth," and "inequality" in the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle represent cause and effect. In the model, inequality and growth affect each other and both of them affect absolute poverty.[2]
Bourguignon defines the change in poverty as a function of growth, distribution, and changes in distribution: Δ poverty ≡ F(growth, distribution, Δ distribution). This equation assumes small changes in poverty.[3] Bourguignon uses per capita income (GDP per capita) as the measure of growth and the Gini Index as the measure of inequality in his model.[6]
Significance
The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle model differs from previous models of poverty in that it looks at the interactions between growth and inequality, rather than considering the two separately. On the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle, the bottom points of the triangle are boxed together under the heading of "development strategy," because Bourguignon believed the mix of policies to reduce poverty should depend on that relationship between growth and inequality.[2]
The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle model implies that reducing poverty requires a combination of country-wide policies focused on growth and country-wide policies focused on reducing inequality. Development strategies that focus on only one of these miss opportunities to reduce absolute poverty. The model describes that a change in inequality affects absolute poverty in two ways. First, a change in relative poverty affects absolute poverty by immediately changing the number of people below the poverty line. Second, a change in relative poverty changes the growth elasticity of poverty. A redistribution of income means more poverty reduction for a given amount of growth. The consequence of this is that policies that focus only on growth without considering distribution limit poverty reduction in two ways.[7][8] Economists theorize that for this reason sub-Saharan Africa and other less developed countries will not be able to meet poverty goals like the Millennium Development Goals through growth alone.[9]
Controversy
Critics argue that the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle looks at aggregate concepts in a way that ignores the processes behind those concepts. Critics say terms like "poverty," "inequality," and "growth" are too broad. Instead, critics suggest that poverty should be traced back to individual behavior.[10] Developmental economists Abhijit Banerjee and Esther Duflo argue that cross-country data cannot be used to give any meaningful insight on topics like poverty and inequality.[10]
Critics also argue that the simplified nature of the model means that it misses factors that affect absolute poverty. Poverty itself can be considered a barrier for economic growth, meaning that the Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle would need to consider the effect of poverty on growth.[5] Other economists argue that the triangle should include financial instability, crises, the business cycle, and their effects on poverty. Finally, many economists believe that there is a strong link between education, literacy rates, and poverty, and that the focus on decreasing poverty should lie in targeting these areas in addition to inequality and growth.[11]
See also
References
- ↑ Gelaw, Fekadu (August 2009). "The Relationship between Poverty, Inequality, and Growth in the Rural Ethiopia: Micro Evidence" (PDF). Retrieved 4 November 2014.
- 1 2 3 4 5 6 Bourguignon, François (February 2004). "The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle" (PDF). World Bank Website. Retrieved 31 October 2014.
- 1 2 "The Growth-Inequality-Poverty Triangle Implication for the Development Strategy in Developing Countries" (PDF). Egyptian Center for Economic Studies. December 2004. Retrieved 31 October 2014.
- ↑ Aigbokhan, Ben E. (February 2008). "Growth, Inequality, and Poverty in Nigeria" (PDF). Retrieved 5 November 2014.
- 1 2 Khan, Muhammad Azhar; Khan, Muhammad Zahir; Zaman, Khalid; Hassan, Umar; Umar, Sobia (July 2013). "Global estimates of growth–inequality–poverty (GIP) triangle: evidence from World Bank's classification countries". Retrieved 5 November 2014.
- ↑ Lopez, J. Humberto (September 2004). "Pro-poor growth: a review of what we know (and of what we don't)" (PDF). Retrieved 5 November 2014.
- ↑ Grammy, Abbas; Assane, Djeto (November 2006). "The Poverty-Growth-Inequality Triangle Hypothesis: An Empirical Examination" (PDF). Journal of Policy Model. Retrieved 31 October 2014.
- ↑ Kapoor, Radhicka. "Inequality Matters" (PDF). ICRIER. Retrieved 31 October 2014.
- ↑ Naschold, Felix (March 2002). "Inequality Briefing" (PDF). Overseas Development Institute. Retrieved 5 November 2014.
- 1 2 Ferreira, Francisco H.G. (November 2012). "Distributions in Motion: Economic Growth, Inequality, and Poverty Dynamics". In Jefferson, Philip N. The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Poverty. Oxford University Press. pp. 427–462.
- ↑ Chemili, Leila; Smida, Mourir (May 2013). "Interaction between Poverty, Growth, and Inequality during the Crisis: A Panel Data Study". Retrieved 4 November 2014.